Vol. 78, No. 5, May
2005
The Future of the Economic Loss Doctrine in Wisconsin
Recent court decisions seem to indicate that there is a concerted
effort to rethink the economic loss doctrine. The question is, is the
Wisconsin Supreme Court ready to articulate an economic loss doctrine
with a well-defined and logical reach?
by R. Thomas Cane & Sheila
Sullivan
n Nov. 9, 2004, the Wisconsin
Supreme Court unanimously held in Insurance Co. of North America v.
Cease Electric Inc. that "the economic loss doctrine does not apply
to contracts for services."1 Neither of the
primary justifications for the doctrine, the court explained, supported
the doctrine's extension to service contracts.2 The court said that because the Uniform Commercial
Code (U.C.C.) does not apply to service contracts, the legislative
scheme embodied in the code would not be "upset" by recognizing tort
remedies in such cases. The court also concluded that tort law provides
a greater incentive than does contract law to guard against negligent
conduct in the provision of services. The court ended its opinion in
Cease with the observation that applying the doctrine to service
contracts could implicate lawsuits against professionals, which
traditionally lie in both tort and contract. A bright line rule would
thus, the court determined, limit the uncertainty and increased
litigation that would accompany any other result.
One of the riskiest forms of gambling is attempting to predict the
future course of the law from a single court decision. Evidence
suggests, however, that Cease may only be the beginning of a
concerted effort to rethink the economic loss doctrine. Before
Ceasewas decided, the court had already agreed to hear cases
dealing with the other-property and fraud-in-the-inducement exceptions
to the doctrine.3 In December, the court
turned this trio of cases into a four-of-a-kind by accepting Linden
v. Cascade Stone Co.,which implicates, among other things, the
integrated systems test for economic loss.4
Equally important for a possible change in course, the appointment of
Justice Diane Sykes to the federal bench removes the court's most ardent
exponent of expanding the reach of the economic loss doctrine. Given
what appears to be a collective agreement that the time is right to
address economic loss, the question is thus whether the Wisconsin
Supreme Court is ready to articulate "an economic loss doctrine rule
with a well-defined and logical reach."5
|
Cane
|
|
Sullivan
|
The Hon. R. Thomas Cane, Marquette 1964, is chief
judge for the Wisconsin Court of Appeals.
Sheila Sullivan, U.W. 2004 magna cum laude, Order of
the Coif, is law clerk for Judge Cane.
The Origins of the Economic Loss Doctrine
The economic loss doctrine is, in its purest form, a judicially
created doctrine that bars commercial purchasers of goods from
recovering solely economic losses from manufacturers under tort theory.
The first formulations of the doctrine reflect its origins as an
intended limit to the products liability torts of negligence and strict
liability.
A National Response to the Emergence of Products
Liability. While products liability law grew out of a policy
judgment that people needed "more protection from dangerous products
than is afforded by the law of warranty,"6
the economic loss doctrine's initial formulations reflect the related
fear that the legislative scheme embodied in the U.C.C. would be undone
if parties were allowed to recover for purely economic losses caused by
defective products. This fear gave rise to the quasi-apocalyptic vision
of contract law "drown[ing] in a sea of tort," which has become the
mantra of those dedicated to expanding the doctrine of economic
loss.7
The New Jersey Supreme Court was the first court to consider whether
the availability of tort claims would allow parties to circumvent U.C.C.
rights and remedies. In 1965, that court held in Santor v. A. &
M. Karaghensianthat the U.C.C. did not provide the exclusive
remedies available for cases arising out of commercial transactions; if
the product was defective, the buyer could bring an action under either
strict products liability law or the U.C.C. warranty and contract
provisions.8
The second court to address the issue came to a different conclusion.
In Seeley v. White Motor Co., the California Supreme Court
produced what became both the classic formulation of, and the most
influential policy justification for, the economic loss doctrine.9 The court observed that the doctrine of strict
liability in tort was designed not to undermine the U.C.C. but rather to
compensate for its inadequacies. The distinction between tort recovery
for physical injury and warranty recovery for economic loss did not rest
on the "luck" of one plaintiff in having an accident that caused injury
while another suffered only damage to a product. The distinction was one
of principle and policy. Society has decided that a buyer should not
bear the risk that a product will cause physical injury, but the buyer
should bear the risk that the "product will not match his economic
expectations."10
In the decades that followed, it became clear that California's
approach to economic loss reflected the prevailing wisdom of a
generation of jurists. The debate embodied in Santor and
Seeley remains significant, however, because it reveals how much
the long history of tort law's development dictated the judicial
response.11 Against the backdrop of an
evolution some saw as too rapid or too extreme, it was logical that
courts would eventually seek a point of equilibrium, a rule that would
stabilize the relationship between tort law and contract law.
Legal historians disagree over whether the economic loss doctrine
achieved that end in its early years.12 By
the late 1980s, in the wake of the U.S. Supreme Court's first
recognition of the doctrine, however, application of the doctrine began
to expand in a way that, for some critics at least, now threatens to
drown tort in a sea of contract.13
In 1986, in East River S.S. Corp. v. Transamerica Delaval
Inc., the U.S. Supreme Court held that the economic loss doctrine
barred tort claims when "a defective product purchased in a commercial
transaction malfunctions, injuring only the product itself."14 East River rejected both the
Santor court's choice of remedies and the Santor court's
efforts to distinguish between "disappointed" and "endangered" users of
defective products. The Court embraced Seeley, but reformulated
the policy arguments on which it depended, expanding on the relation
between general theories of contract, the parties' freedom to allocate
risk, and tort constraints on that freedom. Rather than focusing on
links to the U.C.C., East River thus relied on an abstract and
ahistorical characterization of the distinction between tort law and
contract law, a characterization that has, over time, made it easier to
apply economic loss concepts in ways not contemplated by
Seeley.
Wisconsin Recognizes the Economic Loss Doctrine. Two years
after East River, the Wisconsin Supreme Court in Sunnyslope
Grading Inc. v. Miller, Bradford & Risberg Inc. made the
doctrine of economic loss part of Wisconsin law.15 The buyer in the case, Sunnyslope, was a
contractor that purchased defective backhoes from Hein-Werner. Although
Hein-Werner eventually repaired the backhoes, Sunnyslope sued to recover
for replacement parts, labor, down-time investments, and lost profits.
Because the warranty explicitly excluded such damages, Sunnyslope
brought the action in tort. Sunnyslope thus embodied the core
fear that animated Seeley, that a sophisticated party would
attempt to circumvent a contract that allocated risk by resorting to
tort law.
Rather than depending on the broad principles formulated in East
River, however, the Sunnyslope court looked to the U.C.C. for
an authoritative statement of the rules that "govern a transaction
between two commercial parties of relatively equal bargaining
power."16 The court accepted that the duty
to provide a product that functioned to certain expectations was
contractual, citing a Seventh Circuit decision17 and East River as persuasive authority
for its conclusion. But any broader link between the doctrine and
general policy was restricted to the context of summarizing those
nonbinding federal authorities. The court also limited its application
of the economic loss doctrine to cases involving warranties. Under that
limited formulation, the Sunnyslope court did not decide whether
the doctrine applied to parties not in privity, whether it would apply
to inherently dangerous products, and what constituted damage to the
product as distinguished from damage to other property.
Over time, the Wisconsin Supreme Court has answered these questions.
But in the pattern that reflects a broader national one, the development
of the state law has until now been lead - and sometimes apparently
driven - by federal court predictions of how state courts will
decide.18
Sunnyslope's Unanswered Questions. Privity.
Mirroring Seventh Circuit predictions,19
the Wisconsin Supreme Court held in 1998 in Daanen & Janssen v.
Cedarapids Inc. that a remote commercial purchaser was barred from
recovering purely economic losses under strict liability and negligence
theories.20 The Daanen court
characterized its resolution of the privity question as a logical
extension of Sunnyslope. However, the court's analysis did not
reflect Sunnyslope principles.
The Daanen court instead adopted East River's
characterization of the goals of the economic loss doctrine: 1) to
maintain the distinct functions of tort law and contract law; 2) to
protect commercial parties' freedom to allocate economic risk by
contract; and 3) to encourage the commercial purchaser, which is the
party best suited to assess the risk of economic loss, to assume,
allocate, or insure against that risk. In that context, the court
insisted, requiring privity would blur the distinction between tort and
contract, which is a distinction determined by the type of loss alleged.
Although the court recognized that remote purchasers did not actually
negotiate directly for anything, it determined that application of the
doctrine supported the manufacturer's ability to limit liability through
warranties. The courtconcluded that remote commercial purchasers were as
well suited as anyone to protect against the risks caused by
disappointing products.
Daanen's dependence on policy formulations untethered to the
U.C.C., and the decision's rather alarmist rhetoric, mark a significant
shift from Sunnyslope. More substantively, dismissal of privity
remakes the idea of face-to-face negotiation that once stood at the
heart of contract law. In this new consumerist model, remote buyers
"negotiate" by choosing to pay more - and receiving a warranty with few
disclaimers - or pay less - and receiving little or no protection
against potential defects.
Consumer Transactions. Given Daanen's expansive logic,
the supreme court's decision in State Farm Mutual Insurance Co. v.
Ford Motor Co. to apply the doctrine of economic loss to consumer
transactions was not surprising.21 In
State Farm,the consumer transaction was a vehicle sale, and the
product that caused harm only to itself was a Ford Bronco that burned up
while it was parked because of a defect common to Broncos manufactured
in the 1980s.
Writing for the majority, Justice William Bablitch used
Daanen's three-policy justification to structure his analysis.
Focusing on the loss alleged, the court displayed no discomfort with
describing a product dangerous enough to require a general recall as a
product that failed to meet its "purchaser's expectations;" "[w]hether a
product meets a certain level of performance ... is not a matter of
societal interest. Rather the specific functions of a product are a
matter of contract."22 The court also
determined, contrary to Sunnyslope, that "relative bargaining
power is not the touchstone of the economic loss rule, nor even an
element."23 The court finally concluded
that even when a product was sold "as is" the consumer was the best
party to allocate risk.
Justices Shirley Abrahamson and Ann Bradley, who had joined the
Daanen majority,begin what was to become a pattern of dissents in
economic loss cases, arguing that the doctrine should not apply to
products that posed "an unreasonable risk of harm to persons and
property."24 A manufacturer's liability
should not rest on the fortuitous circumstance of a defective product
not actually causing injury. Nor should fortuity alter the policy
decision that manufacturers can best prevent dangerously defective
products from injuring society.
Although State Farm suggested that economic loss principles
would be consistently applied to consumer transactions, the majority did
not "reach the issue of the preclusion of a strict liability claim where
the parties are of unequal bargaining power, the product is a necessity,
no alternative source for the product is readily available, and the
purchaser cannot reasonably insure against consequential
damages."25 State Farm thus did not
foreclose the possibility of the development of a meaningful exception
to the doctrine for certain classes of consumer transactions.
Dangerous Products. In Northridge Co. v. W.R. Grace
Co., the supreme court considered a commercial transaction involving
a different kind of dangerous product, asbestos.26 The defendant was a seller of asbestos-based
fireproofing material that the plaintiff, Northridge, had installed in
its shopping center.
The supreme court found that Northridge's claim that the product
contaminated the building was an allegation "that a defect in the
product caused physical harm to property ... other than the product
itself."27 The court accepted the argument
that the fireproofing material had not failed to perform the function
for which it was purchased: it protected against fire. Despite its
effectiveness as a commercial product, however, the court concluded that
the fireproofing material had harmed the building by causing an
unreasonable risk to health and safety.That harm was not visible, and
the damages claimed were typical of those associated with economic
loss.The court nevertheless determined that asbestos defects implicated
safety, not suitability, and therefore were best addressed through tort
law, not contract law.
In 1999 the supreme court revisited Northridge when it was
asked in Wausau Tile Inc. v. County Concrete Corp. to "determine
the nature, extent and scope of the public policy exception to the
economic loss doctrine."28 The problematic
product in Wausau Tile was a concrete that caused pavers
(concrete blocks manufactured for commercial use) to crack and curl.
Employing Daanen's tripartite policy framework, the court
first held that the economic loss doctrine barred Wausau Tile's claims.
It then rejected any Northridge exception. The cases were
different, the majority concluded, because the defects alleged were
different. In Wausau Tile, the cement was unsuited for use in
pavers; in Northridge, the asbestos was unreasonably dangerous
but performed adequately as fireproofing. But while the court found in
Wausau Tile that there was no "broad public safety exception" to
the doctrine of economic loss, it did not determine how narrow that
exception was, concluding simply that "the facts of this case do not
involve asbestos or any other material which is inherently dangerous to
the health and safety of humans."29 It is
thus unclear whether the doctrine bars claims relating to products such
as lead-based paint, which share important qualities with asbestos.
Damage to Other Property. The last issue left unanswered by
Sunnyslope was under what circumstances damage to "other
property" would be held to have occurred, thereby taking the claim
outside the scope of economic loss. East River decided that
damage caused to a turbine by a disintegrating ring was not damage to
"other property" because the turbine was sold as an "integrated
package."30 That same year the Seventh
Circuit adopted the logic of East River, holding that when a
complex machine caused damage to itself, there was no damage to "other
property."31
Four years later, the Wisconsin Court of Appeals came to a similar
conclusion in Midwhey Powder Co. v. Clayton Indus.32 Midwhey belonged to a cooperative that installed
an on-site energy production system. After installation, the steam
generator produced poor quality steam that damaged the generator and the
turbines attached to it. Midwhey argued that the damage done to the
turbines authorized a tort claim for economic loss. Drawing on East
River and federal predictions, the court disagreed: "a steam
generator and a turbine may in other circumstances be sufficiently
functionally distinct to be regarded as a separate property ...
[but] when each is a component of a single system integrally connected
... as part of an apparatus designed to produce electricity," turbines
cease to be separate property.33 What
determines integral relation and component status, the court implied,
was the product purchased by the buyer. In 1999 the Wisconsin Supreme
Court acknowledged the integrated system rule, but the court has not
provided any direct guidance on how that rule might be limited.34
To complicate matters further, the U.S. Supreme Court has rejected a
definition of the "product itself" that would have expanded "tort damage
immunity beyond that set" by previous precedent.35 In Saratoga Fishing Co. v. J.M. Martinac
& Co., the Court held that while a ship was the product itself
when it left the initial seller's hands, equipment added by that buyer
and passed on with the ship to another buyer did not become part of the
"product." Although the Saratoga Fishing majority claimed the
implications of its decision were limited, Justice Scalia's dissent
identified the larger question raised by the opinion: whether courts
should look to the product purchased by the plaintiff or the product
sold by the defendant.36 Saratoga
Fishing's resolution of that question suggested a resistance to
definitions of "other property" that destroyed traditional tort
claims.
The New Battle Ground: Exceptions for Intentional Torts? The
most hotly contested economic loss doctrine question today is whether
the doctrine bars claims based on intentional torts such as fraud in the
inducement. Resolution of the question also has implications for the
continued survival of common-law tort claims. In the familiar pattern of
federal courts initiating new applications of the doctrine, the Seventh
Circuit answered this question first, finding no basis for treating
intentional misrepresentation claims differently than other
misrepresentation claims when applying the doctrine of economic
loss.37
In the same year, inRaytheon Co. v. McGraw-Edison Co., the
Eastern District of Wisconsin predicted that Wisconsin state courts
would recognize a limited exception, based on Huron Tool,38 to the doctrine for fraud in the inducement when
the tort was not entwined with the subject of the contract.39 Rejecting policy arguments about the social
costs of fraud, Raytheon concluded that the risk of intentional
deceit could be addressed with a "simple warranty."40 Another Eastern District court disagreed.41 Stressing this state's history of recognizing
distinctions between intentional and negligent misrepresentation, the
court predicted in Budgetel that if Wisconsin courts applied the
doctrine to intentional torts at all, they would provide an exception
for fraud in the inducement broader than Huron.
A year later, the Wisconsin Court of Appeals took up the
question.42 Douglas-Hanson Co. v. BF
Goodrich Co. focused on an allegedly intentional misrepresentation
by B.F. Goodrich - that it had a commercially viable product it could
deliver for processing - that induced Douglas-Hanson to buy and retrofit
an electron beam processor. When Goodrich's product failed to
materialize, Douglas-Hanson sued, alleging, among other claims,
intentional misrepresentation.
The court of appeals assumed that any potential claims were
"interwoven" with the contract, but the court nevertheless concluded
that the economic loss doctrine did not bar intentional
misrepresentation claims when those misrepresentations fraudulently
induced entry into a contract. According to Douglas-Hanson,
Wisconsin's long recognition that parties need a background of truth and
fair dealing in commercial relationships made such misrepresentations a
special situation by undermining the innocent party's ability to
negotiate.
After agreeing to review Douglas-Hanson in 2000, the supreme
court issued a per curiam statement that "the court is equally divided
on the question of whether the public decision of the court of appeals
... should be affirmed."43
Douglas-Hanson was thus affirmed without the binding authority of
supreme court precedent. That left the Seventh Circuit free, in Home
Valu, to predict again that Wisconsin would choose a narrow
Huron Tool-style exception,44
setting up a paradoxical situation in which federal fraud in the
inducement cases would be decided by one version of Wisconsin law and
state cases by another.
In 2003, the Wisconsin Supreme Court appeared to fulfill Seventh
Circuit predictions, holding in Digicorp Inc. v. Ameritech Corp.
that "Wisconsin recognizes a narrow fraud in the inducement exception
... such as the one adopted in Huron Tool."45 The court was so divided, however, that it was
difficult to know what Digicorp really meant:
"A majority of this court, Justices Crooks, Prosser and Sykes,
rejects the broad exception ... adopted in Douglas-Hanson.
However, because Justice Sykes would not adopt any fraud exception,
there is also a majority of this court, Justices Bradley, Bablitch and
Sykes, that rejects the narrow exception ... adopted by ...
Huron Tool ... Two Justices, Bradley and Bablitch, dissent
stating that the Douglas-Hanson exception should apply. A
majority holds that a fraud in the inducement exception to the economic
loss doctrine exists, but there is an even split as to what the fraud in
the inducement exception entails. While four Justices agree that there
should be an exception, only two Justices, Crooks and Prosser, agree
that the Huron Tool exception should be adopted."46
The supreme court returned to the fraud in the inducement question in
2004. In an opinion authored by Justice Sykes, the Tietsworth v.
Harley- Davidson Motor Co. majority made it clear that
Digicorp "did not produce the necessary agreement for an
element-specific fraud-in-the-inducement tort cause of action as an
exception to the economic loss doctrine." However, the court did not
announce a new rule.47 As Chief Justice
Abrahamson observed, determining the "scope of the fraud in the
inducement exception" was thus left "for another day."48
The Future of the Doctrine
Cease's doctrinal pronouncements appear to reject the path
laid out by expansive federal predictions.49 Like Sunnyslope, Cease recognizes the
existence of U.C.C. rights and remedies as "one of the critical
rationales underlying the economic loss doctrine."50 Perhaps as important, Cease subjects the
Daanen policies to the lens of realism, rejecting any assumption
of prenegotiated liability based on general contract theory because it
flies "in the face of the reality of routine service contract
relationships."51 Cease thus
abandons the abstract justifications of East River in favor of a
rationale embodied in Seeley and Sunnyslope and grounded
in the U.C.C.
The court's treatment of real estate, another non-U.C.C. area,
reflects a similar concern about extending the economic loss doctrine
outside the traditional U.C.C. world. The Wisconsin Court of Appeals
applied the doctrine to real estate in Mose v. Tedco Equities,
barring a plaintiff who knowingly purchased contaminated land from
bringing a tort action against the seller.52 In 2002 the court of appeals extended the
doctrine to all real estate contracts.53
The supreme court recently agreed, in Van Lare v. Vogt Inc.,
that economic loss principles barred claims based on strict liability
misrepresentation in the context of commercial real estate
transactions.54 But Van Lare
constrained the applicability it recognized. "[W]e do not decide today
whether the broader conceptualization of the economic loss doctrine in
Tietsworth covers all real estate transactions."55 A situation governed by "a written,
bargained-for contract for the sale of commercial-use land between two
sophisticated parties represented by counsel in the negotiation process"
was, the court observed, "tailor made for the application of traditional
contract law."56
Although the Van Lare court found no exception for strict
liability misrepresentation in commercial cases, it cited, without
comment, the certification memorandum's suggestion that "strict
liability misrepresentation may well apply in situations where the
parties are not in equal bargaining positions or the purchaser may not
be in the best position to assess the risk of economic loss - two
assumptions upon which the economic loss doctrine rests."57 This reference strengthens the impression that
Van Lare applies only to parties who inhabit the model U.C.C.
world.
Together Cease and Van Lare suggest a court poised to
rethink the recent evolution of the economic loss doctrine. The Florida
Supreme Court, in a similar mood, characterized that evolution as one
that had gone too far: "[u]nfortunately, our subsequent holdings have
appeared to expand the rule beyond its principled origins and have
contributed to applications of the rule ... to situations well
beyond our original intent."58 To the
extent that Cease re-roots the doctrine of economic loss in the
policy soil of Sunnyslope - and the U.C.C. - the decision signals
a return to the doctrine's principled origins.
Whether that return will provide the foundation for a doctrine with a
"well-defined and logical reach" depends, however, on the holdings in
Kaloti,59 Grams, and
Linden. Kaloti may determine whether Wisconsin will retain
traditional causes of action for fraudulent inducement or embrace a
regime in which protection against intentional deceit is a private
matter, to be addressed by contract or price. Grams, in which the
plaintiffs seek damages for injuries to calves caused by a defective
milk replacer, and Linden, in which improperly applied stucco
siding damaged a new house, may decide whether a fixed line between
damage to the product and damage to other property can be established.
The opinions in those cases might also tell us whether an "integrated
system" comprehends not just manufactured goods, but corporately
produced products, such as homes, and natural products, like land
itself.60 Clear answers to those questions
will create greater certainty for potential litigants. Answers based on
a common and coherent policy rationale could help reestablish state
court control over the development of Wisconsin's economic loss
doctrine.
Endnotes
12004 WI 139, ¶ 2, 276 Wis. 2d
361, 688 N.W.2d 462.
2Id. ¶¶ 36,
40-41.
3See, e.g., Grams v. Milk Prods.
Inc., No. 03-0801 (Wis. Ct. App. June 17, 2004). See also
www.wicourts.gov, WI App. Cert. No. 03-1225, Kaloti Enter's v.
Kellogg Sales (May 12, 2004).
4See Linden v. Cascade Stone
Co., 2004 WI App 184,276 Wis. 2d 267, 687 N.W.2d 823.
5Rich Prod. Corp. v. Kemutec
Inc., 66 F. Supp. 2d 937, 970 (E.D. Wis. 1999).
6East River S.S. Corp. v.
Transamerica Delaval Inc., 476 U.S. 858, 866 (1986).
7Id. at 866 (citing Grant
Gilmore, The Death of Contract 87-94 (1974)).
8Santor v. A. & M.
Karagheusian, 207 A.2d 305 (N.J. 1965). The defective product in
this case was a rug, and the plaintiff was an ordinary consumer. The
court's support for a choice-of-remedies policy was thus articulated in
the context of consumer transactions. Santor stressed the average
consumer's lack of knowledge and opportunity to determine whether goods
purchased were defective. Id. at 311-12.
9Seeley v. White Motor Co.,
403 P.2d 145 (Cal. 1965). The defective product was a truck, but the
context also was a consumer transaction. In rejecting the Santor
position, the court explicitly rejected the idea that the law of
warranty should be "limited to parties in a somewhat equal bargaining
position." Id. at 151. The Seeley concurrence, flatly
rejecting the notion that the history of products liability law compels
"a dichotomy between `economic loss' and other types of damage," argues
cogently for not extending the doctrine of economic loss beyond
commercial transactions based solely on the nature of the damages
alleged. Id. at 154.
10Id. at 151.
11See Eileen Silverstein,
On Recovery in Tort for Pure Economic Loss, 32 U. Mich. J.L.
Reform 403, 409-12 (Spring 1999).
12Compare Christopher
Scott D'Angelo, The Economic Loss Doctrine: Saving Contract Warranty
Law from Drowning in a Sea of Torts, 26 U. Tol. L. Rev. 591, 593-95
(Spring 1995), and Silverstein, supra n.11, at 409-12.
13See, e.g., R.
Joseph Barton, Drowning in a Sea of Contract: Application of the
Economic Loss Rule to Fraud and Negligent Misrepresentation Claims,
41 Wm. & Mary L. Rev. 1789, 1843 (May 2000).
14476 U.S. at 859. Unlike
Santor and Seeley, East River addresses the problem of
economic loss in the context of a classic commercial transaction between
parties who have the knowledge and power to allocate risks.
15Sunnyslope Grading
Inc. v. Miller, Bradford & Risberg Inc., 148 Wis. 2d 910, 921,
437 N.W.2d 213 (1989).
16Id. at 916.
17See, e.g., Wisconsin Power
& Light Co. v. Westinghouse Elec. Corp., 645 F. Supp. 1129, 1136
(W.D. Wis. 1986), aff'd, 830 F.2d 1405 (7th Cir. 1987).
18For a discussion of this larger
national trend, see Thomas Cane & Sheila Sullivan, At a
Crossroads or at Cross-Purposes?: The Future of the Economic Loss
Doctrine in Wisconsin (unpublished essay on file with the authors).
See also James E. Moore, Agristor Leasing v. Spindler:
Economic Loss, Strict Liability and the U.C.C. - What a Mess, 34
S.D. L. Rev. 101 (1989); Ronald R. Pawlack & David W. Moore, The
Role of the Federal Court and the Expansion of the Ambit of Liability of
Manufacturers: Conceptual Approaches and Suggested Solution, 28
Drake L. Rev. 389 (1978-79); Cornelius J. Peck, Comments on Judicial
Creativity, 69 Iowa L. Rev. 1 (1983); Stephen C. Tourek, Thomas H.
Boyd & Charles Schoenwetter, Bucking the "Trend": The Uniform
Commercial Code, the Economic Loss Doctrine, and Common Law Causes of
Action for Fraud and Misrepresentation, 84 Iowa L. Rev. 875 (August
1999).
19See, e.g., Midwest Knitting
Mills Inc. v. United States, 950 F.2d 1295, 1300 (7th Cir.
1991).
20216 Wis. 2d 395, 405, 573
N.W.2d 842 (1998). Daanen involved a corporation that operated
quarries, a manufacturer of rock crushers, and a distributor of the rock
crushers. The manufacturer warranted its products to the distributor,
and the distributor expressly disclaimed any warranties to its
customers.
21See State Farm Mut. Ins. Co.
v. Ford Motor Co., 225 Wis. 2d 305, 348, 592 N.W.2d 201 (1999).
See also General Cas. Co. of Wis. v. Ford Motor Co., 225
Wis. 2d 553, 592 N.W.2d 198 (1999).
22225 Wis. 2d at 315, 320.
23Id. at 321.
24Id. at 350.
25Id. at 348 (citing
Alloway v. General Marine Indus., 695 A.2d 264, 273 (N.J. 1997)
(repudiating Santor)).
26Northridge Co. v. W.R. Grace
Co., 162 Wis. 2d 918, 471 N.W. 2d 179 (1991).
27Id. at 923.
28Wausau Tile Inc. v. County
Concrete Corp., 226 Wis. 2d 235, 539 N.W.2d 445 (1999).
29Id. at 264-65.
30476 U.S. at 867.
31Wisconsin Power & Light
Co., 645 F. Supp. at 1136. The court's analysis reflected its
embrace of the East River premise that damage confined to a
"package," such as a turbine, generator, and other units of machinery,
purchased by the buyer was not damage to "other property."
Id.
32Midwhey Powder Co. v.
Clayton Indus., 157 Wis. 2d 585, 591-92, 460 N.W.2d 426 (Ct. App.
1990).
33Id.
34See Wausau Tile, 226
Wis. 2d at 249 (citing East River, 476 U.S. at 671-72);
Midwest Helicopters Airways Inc. v. Sikorsky Aircraft, 849 F.
Supp. 666, 671-72 (E.D. Wis. 1994); Midwhey, 157 Wis. 2d at
590-91; Restatement (Third) of Torts § 21 cmt.; Casa Clara
Condo. Ass'n v. Charley Toppino & Sons Inc., 620 So. 2d 1244,
1447 (Fla. 1993); Trans States Airlines v. Pratt & Whitney Canada
Inc., 177 Ill. 2d 21, 682 N.E.2d 45 (1977).
35Saratoga Fishing Co.
v. J.M. Martinac & Co., 520 U.S. 875, 880-81 (1977).
36Id. at 889-90.
37Cooper Power Sys. Inc. v.
Union Carbide Chems. & Plastics Co., 123 F.3d 675, 682 (7th Cir.
1997) (citing no authority for this proposition). The court noted that
all the misrepresentations in the case were about the product itself and
then, sidestepping any reference to the U.C.C. and common-law causes of
action, concluded broadly that "commercial disputes ought to be resolved
according to the principles of commercial law." Id. at 683.
38Huron Tool & Eng'g Co.
v. Precision Consulting Servs. Inc., 209 Mich. App. 365, 532 N.W.2d
541 (1995) (limiting the exception to situations in which fraud is
"extraneous" to the contract). Explicitly underscoring its distance from
Seeley and Sunnyslope, the court in Huron Tool
flatly announced, without citation to authority, that the doctrine of
economic loss "is not limited to the U.C.C." Id. at 374.
39Raytheon Co. v.
McGraw-Edison Co. 979 F. Supp. 858, 870-71 (E.D. Wis. 1997).
Raytheon bought contaminated property from McGraw-Edison and sued to
recover for a variety of damages. The court recognized that, because
federal law required Raytheon to clean up the contamination, the suit
could be seen as being about a safety hazard. Id. at 867. The
court was persuaded, however, that the land was more like a "defective
product" and concluded that any fraud or intentional misrepresentation
was related only to the quality of the product, and therefore the claims
fell within the doctrine of economic loss. Id. at 873-74.
40Id. at 873. See also
Ice Bowl L.L.C. v. Weigel Broadcasting Co., 14 F. Supp. 2d 1080
(E.D. Wis. 1988) (adopting the same position).
41See Budgetel Inns Inc. v.
Micros Sys. Inc., 8 F. Supp 1137 (E.D. Wis. 1988). See also on
reconsideration Budgetel II, 34 F. Supp. 720 (E.D. Wis.
1999).
42See Douglas-Hanson Co. v. BF
Goodrich Co., 229 Wis. 2d 132, 598 N.W.2d 262 (Ct. App. 1999),
overruled in part by Tietsworth v. Harley Davidson Motor Co.,
2004 WI 32, ¶ 32, 270 Wis. 2d 146, 677 N.W.2d 233.
43Douglas-Hanson Co. v.
BF Goodrich Co., 2001 WI 22, ¶ 1, 233 Wis. 2d 276, 607 N.W.2d
621.
44See Home Valu Inc. v. Pep
Boys, 213 F.3d 960, 964-65 (7th Cir. 2000).
45Digicorp Inc. v. Ameritech
Corp., 2003 WI 54, ¶ 3, 262 Wis. 2d 32, 662 N.W. 2d 652.
46Id. at ¶ 5 n.2.
47-2004 WI 32, ¶ 34, 270
Wis. 2d 146, 677 N.W.2d 233. Plaintiffs were members of a proposed class
who wanted to sue Harley Davidson for negligence, strict products
liability, common law fraudulent concealment, and deceptive trade
practices. Id. at 7. They claimed to have been injured by their
reliance on Harley Davidson's representations that the motorcycles they
bought, which had a propensity for engine failure, were of "premium
quality." Id. ¶ 8.
48Id. ¶ 73
(Abrahamson, C.J., dissenting).
49The ruling directly contradicts
Seventh Circuit predictions. See Wausau Paper Mills Co. v. Chas. T.
Main Inc., 789 F. Supp. 968, 974 (W.D. Wis. 1992). See also
Stoughton Trailers Inc. v. Henkel Corp, 965 F. Supp 1227, 1235 (W.D.
Wis. 1997).
502004 WI 139, ¶ 32.
51Id. ¶ 45.
52See Mose v. Tedco
Equities, 228 Wis. 2d 848, 598 N.W.2d 594 (Ct. App. 1999). Mose
reviewed an environmental assessment before purchasing the contaminated
land, and Tedco agreed, as a condition of the sale, to remediate the
contamination. Id. at 852. When Tedco did not clean up the
property, Mose sued. Id. As authority for the proposition that
the economic loss doctrine applied to contaminated real estate, the
court of appeals adopted Raytheon's analysis: "[w]e have not been
provided with, nor do we discern any reason to forego application of the
economic loss doctrine simply because the `product' is real estate."
Id. at 859.
53See Kailin v. Armstrong,
2002 WI App 770, ¶ 27, 252 Wis. 2d 676, 643 N.W.2d 132 (expanding,
in a single sentence, application of the doctrine to all transactions
involving real estate).
54See Van Lare v. Vogt
Inc., 2004 WI 110, ¶ 2, 274 Wis. 2d631, 683 N.W.2d 46. Van Lare
purchased a gravel pit from Vogt; the option to purchase contained a
warranty that Vogt had no knowledge or notice of contaminants,
underground tanks, or other defects. Id.. ¶ 4. Years after
the sale, evidence of dumping was discovered. Van Lare originally sued
under intentional misrepresentation, negligent misrepresentation, and
strict liability misrepresentation but eventually proceeded only under
strict liability. Id. ¶¶ 11, 13.
55Id. ¶ 21.
56Id.
57Id. ¶ 32.
58Moransais v. Heathman,
744 So. 2d 973, 981 (Fla. 1999).
59In Kaloti, the alleged
fraud did not directly pertain to the quality of the goods, food
products, that are the subject of the contract but rather to concealing
a new marketing strategy that made it impossible for the buyers, food
wholesalers, to distribute those products. www.wicourts.gov,
WI. App. Certification No. 03-1225, p. 6.
60Linden also potentially
presents the question of the proper test to use for determining whether
a contract is for goods or services.
Wisconsin
Lawyer